The Complex Art of Decision-Making

The decision-making process explained by behavioral economics

This blog attempts to synthesize many previous posts (links provided in text) on ground-breaking theories of behavioral economics. It will synthesize those into a single view of the decision-making process influenced by various cognitive forces.

Possibly, this view is incomplete or scientifically incorrect somewhere. Still, it is intended to give you a scent of the ultimate complexity of what we think happens simply because we're smart.  

The formula of decision-making

Decision-making is a process of identifying alternative courses of action and selecting the appropriate one for the particular situation considering value-relevant consequences.

This definition provides a simple formula: decision-making = judgment + choice.

The first helps us identify available options, and the second takes on the selection task.

The theory of bounded rationality

As the father of bounded rationality, Herbet Simon, said: "Human behavior is intendedly rational but only limited so."

We believe in making rational judgments while we're uneven in our cognitive abilities, operate with imperfect information, and are limited in time and resources.

All of that leads us to "satisficing" - selecting not the option with the highest utility (wealth, satisfaction, happiness) but the easiest one to achieve within the limitations of the task.

Satisficing and multitasking

So, "satisfice" is a slang word composed of "satisfy" and "suffice." 

Visualizing it is equally simple - you may strive for maximum utility, which is out there in the infinity area of a linear graph between an effort and a value. 

Satisficing and multitasking

Usually, we don't reach the horizon and stop somewhere midway, which is that "good enough" spot representing the sufficient value paid off by decent effort.

Here we almost forgot to account for the mandatory element of today's work - multitasking. We can barely concentrate on a single task and develop up to the extremum.

Instead, we conduct multiple jobs simultaneously, linearly dependent on effort. 

Furthermore, each individual has a productivity threshold, post which the output deteriorates even further. So, the number of tasks develops linearly, while the time to accomplish those tasks suddenly increases.

That breaking point of no. of tasks vs. time to accomplish could be the "satisficing" point, post which an individual becomes nearly unproductive.

The graphical representation of the bounded rationality theory may be as simple as the following one,

Bounded rationality visualization

Allais Paradox

As early as 1952, Maurice Allais objected to the rational choice theory, assuming that we shouldn't consider the rationality of choice but the rationality of the decision-maker.

His experiments proved that people look for the reliability of decisions instead of the maximum utility. 

E.g. most of us would choose A and C options in the following scenarios:

Option А: 100% win of 1 mln francs
vs.
Option В: 89% chance to win 1 mln francs, 10% chance to win 5 mln francs, 1% chance of no-win.

Option C: 10% chance to win 5 mln francs, 90% chance of no-win
vs.
Option D: 11% chance to win 1 mln francs, 89% chance of no-win.

In fact, a rational economic actor would've opted for scenarios B and D, where 1% of additional risk would provide an opportunity to win 390,000 francs more.  

Prospect theory: our judgments depend on a subjective anchor

Prospect theory went further on Allais' findings and explained specific patterns of our behavior when operating under bounded rationality conditions.

Most importantly, our judgments depend not on the maximum utility but on the marginal one compared to our subjective reference point - an anchor. 

The theory of regret

Regret theory assumes that an option's expected utility depends on the regret one may experience by comparing the outcomes of that option to the results of rejected options. 

We regret when the outcome of the rejected option would have been better and rejoice when the rejected option would have been worse.

Interestingly, our judgments are influenced by both anticipated regret (the anticipation of regret caused by manipulating expected feedback on future options) and post-decision one (disappointment from comparing the utility of the selected option with unchosen ones).

Post-decision regret influences our decisions by creating experiences that affect our future anticipated regret.

Basically, we fear the choice consequences in advance and try to minimize our post-decision regret by making regret-averse choices.

Cognitive dissonance 

Cognitive dissonance is related to 
  • the net desirability of the chosen and unchosen options and 
  • the importance of the decision.
Making a decision can cause dissonance, especially if the chosen and unchosen alternates have similar net benefits and if the decision is essential. That can send us into a cycle of rumination, causing regret and anxiety.

Accountability

As we're making important decisions, we may experience post-decision regret and even anxiety due to accountability for the outcomes of our decisions. 

Therefore, we prefer decisions that are easier justifiable in the face of accountability to those with the highest benefits. 

Decision-making in the face of conflicting cognitive forces

The following scheme tries to visualize the extreme complexity of decision-making in the face of many conflicting forces.

Multiple forces affecting the decision-making
Indeed, the rational decisions providing maximum utility are the actual work of art. 

Assuming how many decisions we make regularly, there must be times when we stand back and reflex on the quality and driving forces of our decisions. Arguably, many of those won't be sufficiently rational. 

There's not much glory in being a decision-maker. Instead, it's a challenging and primarily unpleasant job of fighting many demons and planting the course among cognitive traps to the nearest safe haven.

P.S. If you appreciate hundreds of hours invested in researching and writing this blog, you can buy me a coffee or subscribe for the membership by following this link. Thank you!

Buy me a coffee

                                          https://www.buymeacoffee.com/ukrsedo

Follow this blog banner

To keep receiving new insights and research, please subscribe here


More information on this and other exciting topics could be found in "The Technology Procurement Handbook." It represents 23 years of experience, billions of dollars worth of successful sourcing projects, and 1000s of hours spent on research, analysis, and content creation for the most demanding professional readers.
The Technology Procurement Handbook front page
 

Comments

Popular Posts

The Importance of Supply Chain Collaboration

The Discovery of Procurement Value

The New Looking of Industrial Buying